Shane Smith

About Shane Smith

This author has not yet filled in any details.
So far Shane Smith has created 237 blog entries.
2 06, 2025

Karen Petrou: A New Trade War: Interest on Reserves

2025-06-02T09:16:29-04:00June 2nd, 2025|The Vault|

Clients will recall that, during his first term, Donald Trump nominated Judy Shelton, a frequent monetary-policy commentator, to the Federal Reserve Board.  However, her nomination sparked outrage among Congressional Democrats and many pundits that doomed confirmation.  Ms. Shelton nonetheless remains a trusted adviser to many with the President’s ear, making renomination and, this time, confirmation a strong possibility should Ms. Shelton still want a seat on the Board of Governors.  We thus took notice when she last week posted an attack on the payment of interest by the Fed on balances held by foreign branches and agencies.  She drew in part on another post adding foreign central banks to the complaint.  This might seem a remote or even improbable concern, but so does much else in CEA head Stephen Miran’s proposal positing a “user tax” that’s now in the House reconciliation bill attacking foreign investors.  Ms. Shelton’s complaint should thus be taken very seriously, especially given all the other demands to curtail interest on reserve balances (IORB).

Ms. Shelton finds that foreign branches and agencies get 42 percent of interest payments from the Fed, or about $78 billion based on total interest payments to banks of $186 billion in 2024.  Rates now on IORB stand at about 4.4 percent – one of the very best deals on offer for super-safe, overnight funds.  Another post calculates interest payments to foreign central banks at around $16.5 billion a year.  In short, it’s a lot of money which the posts rightly say …

27 05, 2025

Karen Petrou: Making Liquidity Regulation Make Sense

2025-05-27T09:26:04-04:00May 27th, 2025|The Vault|

Although U.S. regulators remain determined to enact each rule as if it relates to no other, researchers have increasingly found that rules have cumulative and often conflicting purposes – see, for example, the sum total of bank rules which empowered nonbank financial intermediaries operating with impunity until they needed trillions in taxpayer backstops in 2020.   Following a seminal Federal Reserve Bank of New York paper on the cumulative consequences – none good – of considering capital and liquidity rules in isolation, a new BIS paper considers the internal contradictions of consequential liquidity regulation and central-bank backstops.  Now, if only bank regulators at home and abroad did the same.

The BIS paper looks at the push-pull evident in liquidity rules founded on expectations that banks should not use central-bank liquidity even though central banking is founded on the concept of providing liquidity to banks under stress.  As all too evident in the 2023 crisis, liquidity compliance cannot ensure banks stand firm in a run, even as the Fed’s discount window opened with all the alacrity of an centuries-old casement.  Solutions posed ever since have suggested stiffening the liquidity standards and ensuring discount-window operability, but each thread of this debate ignores the other.  The BIS paper happily proposes a framework in which the two pillars of bank resilience under liquidity stress are considered together to craft a sensible benign-scenario liquidity rule along with an effective, disciplined backstop that minimizes moral hazard.

The BIS paper rightly is to avoid so stringent a build-up …

19 05, 2025

Karen Petrou: The Political Buzzsaw Powering Up for the New Powell Policy Paradigm

2025-05-19T09:21:50-04:00May 19th, 2025|The Vault|

Buzz is growing about how the Fed’s promised new monetary-policy construct will do better than the old, failed FAIT.  Last week, Chair Powell offered a teaser, the august Group of Thirty told it what to do, and former Chair Bernanke told the Fed how to tell all about it.  Let’s hope the Fed indeed does better this time, but even if it does, Congress might well block the Fed from doing what it comes to think it must.  When the Fed releases its new plan in the rarefied precincts of Jackson Hole this August, it’s likely to disregard what a very skeptical Congress thinks about it, let alone what might then be done to it either on the Hill or by Mr. Powell’s successor.  Early warning signals show it will be a lot.

The Fed knows it’s at considerable political risk, but not all the ways political risk could strike it down.  Mr. Powell is of course keenly aware that President Trump thinks he’s “Mr. Too Late, a major loser.”  Anticipating still more political push-back, Mr. Powell tried to protect the Fed via a switcheroo early after the election, pulling the Fed back from climate-risk efforts and anything that smacks of reputational-risk supervision.  That may help, but the Fed has yet to reckon with how much Members of Congress want a complete monetary-policy reset forcing the Fed to rely on open-market operations as the principal mechanism of monetary-policy transmission.  Any new Fed policy construct that doesn’t shrink the portfolio, …

12 05, 2025

Karen Petrou: Why Stablecoin Hegemony Could Cost Too Much

2025-05-12T09:49:18-04:00May 12th, 2025|The Vault|

In the battle over stablecoin regulation, defenders of the pending legislation make much of the need for the U.S. to become the dominant global leader.  That’s fine, but what if the new stablecoin framework gives the U.S. crypto preeminence at the cost of U.S. bank resilience and macroeconomic growth?  That would be a high price to pay, but it’s nonetheless the Faustian bargain lurking in the latest legislation.

As our analyses have made clear, the House and Senate bills address only payment stablecoins – i.e., digital assets used by consumers and companies to settle financial accounts or to purchase goods and services.  The idea is to make regulated stablecoins as reliable a medium of exchange as dollars, with the bills’ reserve-asset requirements meant to ensure that one stablecoin dollar always equals one U.S. dollar. This is fine as far as it goes, but that’s not far enough to ensure payment-system finality, ubiquity, and equality.  A more robust stablecoin also does little but make it still more likely that regulated banks will be disintermediated as deposits move from the current, fractional system into a new, “narrow bank” model that does little for anyone but stablecoin issuers, their affiliates, and parent companies such as giant tech platforms.

A dollar’s worth of stablecoins is little more than an abstraction until one knows how it moves across the payment system.  If the payment rails are weak or the engineer is negligent, then armored boxcars just make an even bigger, harder bang when they derail.…

28 04, 2025

Karen Petrou: What Else Should Worry You

2025-04-28T09:41:09-04:00April 28th, 2025|The Vault|

Last week, the Washington Post ran an astonishing article, easily overlooked in the personal-finance section. In it, the writer advised the many consumers she said were besieging her with fearful questions about how best to ensure their money is safe in the bank – and, if they’re still worried, where to buy a nice safe. That same day, a friend asked me if his short-term Treasury bills are safe. These are, of course, anecdotal reports, but such worries are rarely tracked as the leading indicators they are.  It’s obvious in crisis after crisis that, when retail depositors and investors are frightened, we should all be very worried.

How much uncertainty does it take to create a financial or macroeconomic crisis?  None of the Fed’s financial-stability reports deigns to consider consumers, nor does the Fed tell us when to worry because it fears we will if the Fed cracks its stone face.  However, a brand-new Fed study provides a very useful – if frightening – analytical context in which to consider anecdotal data.

The Fed staff paper examines different types of uncertainty and their impact on economic activity and financial conditions. While it doesn’t directly extend the analysis to financial stability, the results are important given the strong correlation between economic and financial volatility and very, very bad financial-market events.

The paper assesses six key drivers of uncertainty: real economic conditions, inflation, economic policy, trade policy, geopolitical risk, and financial uncertainty as reflected in the VIX. These uncertainty drivers exploded …

21 04, 2025

Karen Petrou: The Fed Just Puts Ribbons on Rags

2025-04-21T09:14:50-04:00April 21st, 2025|The Vault|

Four months after announcing plans for minimal changes to its stress tests, the Fed last Thursday screwed up its courage and proposed a couple of them.  The remaining, still-small changes will come after the Fed rests up, but none of this seemingly-strenuous effort addresses the fundamental problem with both capital regulation and the testing designed to ensure it suffices:  none of these rules make total sense on its own and all of them taken together are a cacophony of competing demands and ongoing collisions with other standards.  Prettying up the stress-test rule is thus only putting ribbons on a ragged assemblage of ill-fitting pieces in clashing colors with large, large holes.

Now-ousted VCS Michael Barr promised a “holistic” capital construct during his 2022 confirmation hearings, but he nonetheless clung tightly to one-off rulemakings without any cumulative-impact analysis.  Mr. Barr thus opposed last week’s stress-test changes, but for all the wrong reasons.  He thought they went too far; in fact, they don’t go anywhere near as far as they could and should.

The new stress-test proposal most substantively says that banks will henceforth be judged by a three-year rolling average of their tested capital levels, rather than on the current, volatile annual schedule.  But, averaging numbers that don’t make sense tells one nothing about the utility of each test.  Think about a household with two chihuahuas – average dog weight about ten pounds.  Next year, a Labrador romps in, and the average goes up, but the yard can still hold three …

14 04, 2025

Karen Petrou: The Fed Has Given Itself Nothing But Bad Choices

2025-04-14T09:13:54-04:00April 14th, 2025|The Vault|

Much has been written of late about the pickle in which the Fed finds itself due to the President’s quixotic trade war.  The Fed is indeed facing a dilemma setting monetary policy, but it confronts a Rubik’s Cube trying also to ensure financial stability.  The reason:  the more the Fed fights inflation, the less it can secure the financial system and the more it is forced to secure the financial system, the less able it will be to conduct monetary policy.  This vise results from the Fed’s huge portfolio, yet another example of why the Fed should have reduced its portfolio as quickly as possible after both 2008 and 2020.  Since it didn’t, it now has only bad choices if Treasury-market illiquidity turns toxic.

This negative feedback loop is the result not only of the Fed’s cumbersome trillions, but also of its unwillingness to make another hard decision:  meaningful action to address identified systemic risks.  Had the Fed heeded its own warnings going back to 2020, it might have done something to reduce Treasury-market dependence on high-risk, leveraged hedge funds.  To be fair, the Fed cannot directly regulate hedge funds and the SEC lacks prudential authority, but both agencies had lots of ways to curtail systemic risk long before basis-trading hedge funds came to hold at least $1 trillion in assets.

So far, hedge-fund deleveraging is proceeding in a reasonably-ordered way, but risks such as these have a bad habit of cascading.  Jamie Dimon already anticipates this, but he …

7 04, 2025

Karen Petrou: Why Regulators Will be Flat-Footed if Bad Now Turns Soon to Worse

2025-04-07T09:15:06-04:00April 7th, 2025|The Vault|

One of the comforts with which bank regulators will doubtless console themselves after last week’s market rout is that the largest U.S. banks have the capital not only to withstand this, but also the probable, profound consequences of the President’s punitive tariffs.  However, because U.S. regulators mismeasure capital resilience, this confidence is misplaced.  Using the economic-capital approach I recently endorsed shows that, while U.S. banks still are strong, they are not fortresses.

FedFin recently analyzed two new studies demonstrating that geopolitical risk is hard on bank solvency.  To this, one of course can say that there’s no real-world need for exhaustive studies of dozens of countries over decades – common sense buttressed by history makes this all too clear.  These hard lessons and the data that describe them do, though, make clear that it’s more than worth revisiting the United States after the Smoot-Hawley tariffs to get a sobering idea of the negative feedback loop between geopolitical risk, macroeconomic hazards, bank vulnerability, and – back to the beginning, geopolitical risk. Any talk of the 1930s is alarmist and also inapplicable in numerous respects, but it is the most pertinent example of geopolitical risk over the past century and thus demonstrates the need now to be very, very careful – not something this White House appears to be good at.

Economic-capital measures are a more robust platform to assess bank resilience than regulatory capital and are thus of particular pertinence at this dangerous moment.  Regulatory-capital measurements are so complex and often …

17 03, 2025

Karen Petrou: A New, Unified Theory of Effective Bank Regulation

2025-03-17T09:13:31-04:00March 17th, 2025|The Vault|

There is one perennial, overlooked, and devastating irony in the vast body of bank capital and liquidity regulation:  the better a bank’s liquidity score, the less regulatory capital it has.  Although liquidity and capital are inexorably linked when it comes to preserving bank solvency, the need to comply with two contradictory standards forces banks to change their business model to meet both ends in the middle at considerable cost to profitability and long-term franchise value.  This is of course a major threat to solvency of which bank regulators are either blissfully unaware or, worse, heedless.  Federal banking agencies have stoutly refused to undertake the essential cumulative-impact analysis we’ve fruitlessly urged on them most recently in Congressional testimony.  A new Federal Reserve Bank of New York study shows not just why they should judge rules by sum-total impact, but also how they could do so and thereby have a much better sense of which banks might actually go broke before they do.

I refer you to the full FRB-NY paper for details.  It crafts an economic-capital construct calculated by netting the net present value of financeable assets versus par liabilities as a baseline measure which can then be tested under various stress scenarios that start with illiquidity and end in insolvency and vice versa.  This leads to a robust measure of survivability that combines the impact of credit risk, liquidity, and the real-world market conditions current rules ignore.  In essence, economic capital is derived from the hard-nosed, real-time factors that wise …

24 02, 2025

Karen Petrou: How the White House Could Have Fun with the Fed

2025-02-24T09:11:47-05:00February 24th, 2025|The Vault|

President Trump has an awesome ability to keep even his closest allies perplexed by nonstop announcements that often break precedent, accepted norms, and even the law.  Just as opponents begin to rally against one initiative, the White House launches another, sending dissenters off in a different direction, leaving the actions they initially targeted unchanged or even forgotten. Still, several policy themes are coming through loud and clear through all these different actions that have far-reaching financial-market cumulative impact.  One is the sheer volatility all this chaos creates; another to which I turn here is the President’s sure and certain effort to make the Federal Reserve a tool of the executive branch, going beyond setting interest rates to turn it into America’s sovereign wealth fund.

As we noted, The President’s executive-order barrage includes one demanding a U.S. sovereign wealth fund (SWF).  The tricky bit here is not the lines that would quickly blur between public and private enterprise, an historic U.S. economic principle that won’t slow Mr. Trump down for a minute.  Instead, it’s where the money funding the SWF comes from given the lack of a nationalized commodities enterprise such as Norway’s and the Administration’s hell-bent campaign to reduce the federal deficit.  Solution?  The Fed.

U.S. law is seemingly an obstacle to deploying the Fed as an SWF since it allows the Fed to hold only direct obligations of the U.S. Treasury and its agencies as well as – a Fed sleight of hand in the 2008 crisis – Fannie …

Go to Top